Updating some U.S. House graphics

Now seems like a good time to remake some graphics I use often. All the underlying data are from Voteview.

Below is a party-blind measure of polarization in the U.S. House, from the beginning of that chamber through Wednesday of last week. The party-blind measure is the mean of all pairwise distances. (I once calculated it here for states and first came across it here.) This lets us go back to before the major parties were Republicans and Democrats. It also does not force us to make arbitrary decisions about handling minor parties, independents, and others with less common ways of affiliating/identifying.

Below is the more familiar measure: distance between the median members of the major parties, back to the end of Reconstruction. This plot includes the median Southern Democrat (conventionally the 11 Confederate states plus Kentucky and Oklahoma).

The last two plots answer the question: “How well does an N-dimensional model fit the data?” I used the optimal classification algorithm to recover ideal points for each House. I did this one Congress at a time; see here and here for other options. The black line comes from one-dimensional models. The gray line comes from two-dimensional models. The first plot gives the percentage of votes correctly classified, by Congress.

The second plot gives the aggregate proportional reduction in error.

Here is a CSV of the fit measures above. The first two columns are for the one-dimensional models. The next two are for two dimensions.

For me, “voting system” implies the wrong question

I recently expressed frustration with something I called “voting-system-speak.” This is my attempt to define (or at least engage) that and say why I find it frustrating. The crux, I think, is that many (but not all) who think about electoral reform are coming at the subject from a social-choice perspective. Another key point, which is related, is that we may be able to sort reform proposals based on their handling of the problem of social choice. One class of reforms turns to parties. Another class turns to voters. And the former strikes me as more realistic, based on insights from the field of political behavior.

Continue reading “For me, “voting system” implies the wrong question”

Is “more voter education” the solution?

I have been mentioning this article a lot lately, so I figured I’d blog it. Here are some key excerpts:

More than one in 10 votes were ruled invalid in the multicultural seat of Fowler, raising serious questions about whether explanations of Australia’s compulsory preferential voting system are getting through.

Fowler, in Sydney’s south-west, has one of the highest non-English-speaking populations, many of whom have come to Australia as refugees from countries with very different political systems.

And:

She said the centre had just run a campaign, Civic Spotlight, that aimed to educate migrant communities about the voting system, but more needed to be done.

“The AEC, they are not doing enough to address it. They have resources online and they provide information in several languages but it’s not just about addressing community leaders, it needs to be one-on-one,” she said.

I recently referred to the AEC (Australian Electoral Commission) as one of “the sorts of agencies that like running STV elections.”